Today's Opinions, Tomorrow's Reality
Conjunction Junction,
What Disfunction!
NEW YORK, October 18, 1998 --
Fifty-six minutes after the scheduled
arrival of Amtrak's Northeast Direct train #175 from Boston, the engine
finally rolled into the station. It was a fairly typical Sunday evening
service for Amtrak. As the train began to trudge forward toward its destination
in Washington, DC, the conductor noted no unusual circumstances. "Just
slow," he said. Slow indeed. In the 28 years since the nationalization
of America's passenger rail system, slow, overpriced service has become
the norm. Sadly, Congress once again passed up an opportunity to undo
its 28-year-old misdeed when it authorized $609 million in Amtrak subsidies
as part of the budget agreement last week.1 The same Congress
refused to even hear the Amtrak Privatization Act, sponsored by Rep. Joel
Hefley (R-CO.) The absence of productive legislation is not surprising
given this Congress' shameful record. Last year it passed the ironically
named Amtrak Reform and Accountability Act, which granted a huge $2.3
billion one-time subsidy. The "accountability" is supposedly
based upon the law's weakly enforced goals of financial self-sufficiency
in 2002.2 Given legislators' passion for sending pork-laden Amtrak bills
to their constituents, it is unlikely that Americans will see any real
reform. The debate about whether to continue federal funding
of Amtrak has changed little in the past two decades. Advocates insist
Federal subsidies and control are imperative to prevent the discontinuation
of less profitable Western and Midwestern lines. If a private profit motive
is to replace the public interest, they say, passenger rail service will
be lost to millions of Americans, and communities will be forced to sacrifice
an important part of their heritage. Amtrak's detractors have meanwhile insisted that the
burden of maintaining thousands of miles of underused rail lines hurts
both taxpayers and east coast travelers. It is these passengers -- along
the potentially profitable Northeast Corridor served by train #175 -- that
pay exorbitant rates to help subsidize the rest of the system. The reduced
value offered on this line, where a close, dense population usually makes
rail travel most efficient, leads to economic and environmental losses
as large numbers of would-be train travelers switch to cars and planes.
The time is ripe for change in this debate. Besides the
twenty years additional evidence highlighting free-market efficiency,
private-rail advocates may soon find unlikely allies in the ranks of mass
transportation activists. Faced with urban sprawl problems that rival
Southern California, East Coast cities are struggling to solve their transportation
problems without the need to build horrific new auto-dependent freeway
systems. Advocates of expanded rail-based mass transit have long
been firmly entrenched in the public ownership camp. Since all of the
urban rail systems constructed in the past 30 years have been public ventures,
it is not surprising that they see government leadership as the only solution. But it is instructive to remember that the New York subway -- America's
most extensive and efficient urban rail system -- was built 100 years ago
as a private venture. More recently built urban rail systems, such as
those in Washington, DC, Miami and Los Angeles, are monuments to inefficiency. DC's system, which is nearing completion after almost
30 years of construction, loses almost $100 million per year. It offers
infrequent, unreliable service, despite its envious position of serving
a city with a highly centralized commuting pattern and relatively dense
population. The failure of Miami's Metrorail system to attract even minimal
public usage has earned it the name "Metro-fail."3
Los Angeles' even newer system has become a national laughingstock with
its incredible cost overruns and construction delays. The situation in
L.A. has become so bad that serious discussion has been given to abandoning
construction. The problem with these rail systems, as with Amtrak,
has been a horribly inefficient allocation of resources as government
has attempted to force rail service in places where it is not practical.
Unlike urban rail, however, Amtrak's far-flung service does not enjoy
the support of the environmentalists and urban idealists who have made
up the core of the movement for mass transportation. If these people can
be convinced that privatizing Amtrak and focusing its service on viable
areas advances their agenda, a coalition could be formed that might bring
down the nationalized rail system and have great benefits for the country.
The case for environmentalists should be clear. The inflated
$150 Amtrak ticket price from Washington to New York makes travel by airlines
and automobiles competitive with rail travel. Would-be rail passengers
are thereby forgo the environmentally friendly locomotive for fuel guzzling
cars and airplanes. For underused routes in Western states, this case
is even stronger. Short, empty trains totally eliminate the environmental
advantage of rail transport. The urban idealists should realize that a new private
player in the passenger rail market would greatly expand opportunities
for private participation in urban rail construction. Private efforts
to deliver commuter transportation services have been greatly harmed by
the absence of commercial experience. A reinvigorated American commercial
rail system would help provide practical experience that could once again
deliver private participation in viable urban rail construction. Sadly, any hope for success in this movement will probably
have to wait until the fiscal 2000 budget debate. With luck and effort,
however, Amtrak's detractors will join with mass transit activists to
make American passenger rail in the 21st century as efficient of a means
of transportation as it was a century ago. Notes: 1. Amtrak's Web Site, Congress
To Approve Full Funding For Amtrak, October 16, 1998 2. Government Printing Office, Amtrak
Reform and Accountability Act of 1997 3. The Cato Institute, Cato Handbook for Congress: Urban Policy, 1997 |